Page 460 - untitled
P. 460

KEITH HENNESSEY, DOUGLAS HOLTZ-EAKIN, AND BILL THOMAS                


                           TWO TYPES OF SYSTEMIC FAILURE
         Government policymakers were afraid of large firms’ sudden and disorderly failure
         and chose to intervene as a result. At times, intervention itself contributed to fear and
         uncertainty about the stability of the financial system. These interventions responded
         to two types of systemic failure.

         Systemic failure type one: contagion

         We begin by defining contagion and too big to fail.
            If financial firm X is a large counterparty to other firms, X’s sudden and disorderly
         bankruptcy might weaken the finances of those other firms and cause them to fail.
         We call this the risk of contagion, when, because of a direct financial link between
         firms, the failure of one causes the failure of another. Financial firm X is too big to
         fail if policymakers fear contagion so much that they are unwilling to allow it to go
         bankrupt in a sudden and disorderly fashion. Policymakers make this judgment in
         large part based on how much counterparty risk other firms have to the failing firm,
         along with a judgment about the likelihood and possible damage of contagion.
            Policymakers may also act if they worry about the effects of a failed firm on a par-
         ticular financial market in which that firm is a large participant.
            The determination of too big to fail rests in the minds of the policymakers who
         must decide whether to “bail out” a failing firm. They may be more likely to act if
         they are uncertain about the size of counterparty credit risk or about the health of an
         important financial market, or if broader market or economic conditions make them
         more risk averse.
            This logic can explain the actions of policymakers in several cases in :
                                                   
            • In March, the Fed facilitated JPMorgan’s purchase of Bear Stearns by providing
             a bridge loan and loss protection on a pool of Bear’s assets. While policymakers
             were concerned about the failure of Bear Stearns itself and its direct effects on
             other firms, their decision to act was heightened by their uncertainty about po-
             tential broader market instability and the potential impact of Bear Stearns’ sud-
             den failure on the tri-party repo market.
            • In September, the Federal Housing Finance Agency (FHFA) put Fannie Mae
             and Freddie Mac into conservatorship. Policymakers in effect promised that
             “the line would be drawn between debt and equity,” such that equity holders
             were wiped out but GSE debt would be worth  cents on the dollar. They
             made this decision because banking regulators (and others) treated Fannie and
             Freddie debt as equivalent to Treasuries. A bank cannot hold all of its assets in
             debt issued by General Electric or AT&T, but can hold it all in Fannie or Fred-
             die debt. The same is true for many other investors in the United States and
             around the world–they assumed that GSE debt was perfectly safe and so they
             weighted it too heavily in their portfolios. Policymakers were convinced that
   455   456   457   458   459   460   461   462   463   464   465