Page 114 - untitled
P. 114

CREDIT EXPANSION                                                 


            But elsewhere the economy remained sluggish, and employment gains were frus-
         tratingly small. Experts began talking about a “jobless recovery”—more production
         without a corresponding increase in employment. For those with jobs, wages stag-
         nated. Between  and , weekly private nonfarm, nonsupervisory wages actu-
         ally fell by  after adjusting for inflation. Faced with these challenges, the Fed
         shifted perspective, now considering the possibility that consumer prices could fall,
         an event that had worsened the Great Depression seven decades earlier. While con-
         cerned, the Fed believed deflation would be avoided. In a widely quoted  speech,
         Bernanke said the chances of deflation were “extremely small” for two reasons. First,
         the economy’s natural resilience: “Despite the adverse shocks of the past year, our
         banking system remains healthy and well-regulated, and firm and household balance
         sheets are for the most part in good shape.” Second, the Fed would not allow it. “I am
         confident that the Fed would take whatever means necessary to prevent significant
         deflation in the United States. . . . [T]he U.S. government has a technology, called a
         printing press (or, today, its electronic equivalent), that allows it to produce as many
         U.S. dollars as it wishes at essentially no cost.” 
            The Fed’s monetary policy kept short-term interest rates low. During , the
         strongest U.S. companies could borrow for  days in the commercial paper market
         at an average ., compared with . just three years earlier; rates on three-month
         Treasury bills dropped below  in mid- from  in . 
            Low rates cut the cost of homeownership: interest rates for the typical -year
         fixed-rate mortgage traditionally moved with the overnight fed funds rate, and from
          to , this relationship held (see figure .). By , creditworthy home buy-
         ers could get fixed-rate mortgages for .,  percentage points lower than three
         years earlier. The savings were immediate and large. For a home bought at the me-
         dian price of ,, with a  down payment, the monthly mortgage payment
         would be  less than in . Or to turn the perspective around—as many people
         did—for the same monthly payment of ,, a homeowner could move up from a
         , home to a , one. 
            An adjustable-rate mortgage (ARM) gave buyers even lower initial payments or
         made a larger house affordable—unless interest rates rose. In , just  of prime
         borrowers with new mortgages chose ARMs; in ,  did. In , the propor-
                      
         tion rose to . Among subprime borrowers, already heavy users of ARMs, it rose
         from around  to . 
            As people jumped into the housing market, prices rose, and in hot markets they
         really took off (see figure .). In Florida, average home prices gained . annually
         from  to  and then . annually from  to . In California, those
         numbers were even higher: . and .. In California, a house bought for
         , in  was worth , nine years later. However, soaring prices were
         not necessarily the norm. In Washington State, prices continued to appreciate, but
         more slowly: . annually from  to , . annually from  to . In
                                         
         Ohio, the numbers were . and .. Nationwide, home prices rose . annu-
         ally from  to —historically high, but well under the fastest-growing
         markets.
   109   110   111   112   113   114   115   116   117   118   119